红色中国网

 找回密码
 立即注册
搜索
红色中国网 首 页 红色春秋 查看内容

江苏省在1966-1978年间的经济增长考察

2018-12-27 23:02| 发布者: 龙翔五洲| 查看: 18807| 评论: 1|原作者: 克里斯ㆍ布拉默尔|来自: 人民食物主权

摘要: 这篇文章将毛时代江苏省在1966-1978年间的经济增长,与英国工业革命早期的兰开夏郡和约克郡进行了比照。对比发现,集体时期江苏的工农业发展速度很快,积累了必要的技术和基础设施。可以说,毛时代的经济建设是中国经济腾飞的决定性因素。
注释:

[1]World Bank 1992, 3 & 140.
[2]Dikötter 2016, 263.
[3]Maddison 2010; Wu 2014.
[4]The official verdict wasgiven in On Questions of Party History (1981); see Liuand Wu 1986, 587.
[5]Macfarquhar andSchoenhals 2006; Dikötter 2016; Walder 2015.
[6]Dikötter 2016, 284.
[7]Walder 2015, 321&332-33.
[8]According to People’s Daily(8.11.2013), “We must fully acknowledge….thetremendous achievements in the period before reform and openingup.” Politicalimperatives, namely the need tolegitimate Party rule, have also played a keyrole in developing this two-period’ analysis.
[9]Li 2008; Gao 2008; Han2000; Hinton 1991; Bramall 1993, 2000, and 2007; Blecher2009
[10]The figures for Chinaare my new estimate; see Bramall(forthcoming). For Britain, see Broadberry2015, 289. Regional data alsosuggest that Lancashire and Yorkshire were lowwage counties in around 1770(Hunt 1986, 965). But Broadberry’spessimistic view is controversial; According to Kelly and O'Grada(2014, 7),"...consumption levels [were] comfortably above barebonessubsistence onthe eve of the Industrial Revolution." See also Allen 2009.
[11] Crafts 1985; 2014.
[12]Ho 1994; White 1998.
[13]See JGK 1999, NYTJ 1976, NCJJ 2000 and NYFX 1979.
[14]For the secondary literature on agriculture, see Huang 1990. Forrural industry, Ho 1994, Mo 1987 and Whiting 2001. On industry more generally,Bramall 2007. For useful overviews, see Marton 2000 and White 1998.
[15]Communes routinely under-reported production to avoid procurements(see for example Oi 1989). In addition, the growth surge shown by the officialagricultural data for 1978-1984 is simply too large to be plausible. As Hinton(1991) has argued, the surge reflected under-reporting in 1978 that was largelycorrected by 1984.
[16]Fei 1983; Ma 2008.
[17]The expansion of education is not discussed in this article. Thisis partly because of space constraints, but also because formal education wasless important in driving growth than other factors, notably skills acquiredvia learning-by-doing in industry. For a discussion, see Bramall 2007.
[18]Davis 1979, 94-97; Timmins 1998,85.
[19]Growth rates at constant prices.From SSB 2010.
[20]Jiangsu tongjiju 1989.
[21]'Urban industry' here means allindustrial production in the cities-proper of Nanjing, Wuxi, Xuzhou, Changzhou,Suzhou, Nantong, Lianyungang, Huaiyin, Yancheng, Yangzhou, Taizhou andZhenjiang. All GVIO in county jurisdictions is classified as rural; this ruraldefinition therefore includes the shedui sector but also county-levelcollective and state-owned industries. Although crude, this measure capturesthe breadth of rural industry better than the shedui definition.
[22]The absence of migration controlsduring the Leap—and the subsequent flood of migrantsfrom rural to urban areas—exacerbated the Great Famineby causing rural labour shortages.
[23]For overviews of Chinese ruralindustrialization, see Riskin 1978, Sigurdson 1977, Perkins 1992, He 2004,Dangdai Zhongguo de xiangzhen qiye weiyuanhui 1991; 2009 and Bramall 2007. Forrural industrialization in Jiangsu, see Ho 1994, White 1998, Whiting 2001 andBramall 2007.
[24]This is for GVIO at 1990 prices(Jiangsu tongjiju 1994).
[25]Data at 1980 prices from Jiangsutongjiju 1989, 137 and He 2004, 28 & 31.
[26]In Jiangsu, 17 per cent ofindustrial output originated in the shedui sector in 1978, double the nationalaverage (He 2004, 31; SSB 1990).
[27]Even Dikötter (2016, 279-80)acknowledges Jiangsu's pace of industrialization during the 1970s.
[28]Sunan (southern Jiangsu) is moreaccurate than Jiangnan ('south of the river') because rural industries alsodeveloped rapidly along the north bank of the Yangzi. Useful sources include Mo1987; Zhou 1994; WXG 1990.
[29]Rural Suxichang is defined hereas the counties of Jiangyin, Yixing, Shazhou, Changshu, Taicang, Kunshan,Wujiang, Wuxian, Wuxi (county), Wujin, Jintan and Liyang. Data are for GVIO at1990 constant prices (Jiangsu tongjiju 1994).
[30] Jiangsu tongjiju 1989.
[31]Jiangsu tongjiju 1989, 137; 1994,69. These data are for commune-level industry and higher at 1980 prices. Thefigures exclude counties under the jurisdiction of Nanjing municipality.
[32]JGK 1989, 13-16
[33]Jiangsu tongjiju 1994, 195 &511. The data are for Wuxi and Suzhou cities
[34]Turner 1982, 509. The Lancashirefigures may be exaggerated.
[35]Apostolides 2008, 32 & 34;Broadberry 2015, 88 & 92. 'North' includes Cheshire, Nottinghamshire andStaffordshire.
[36]SSB 2010.
[37]The kouliang (口粮) measures per capita grain distributed by the collective. Reportedkouliang figures under-state total consumption because of outputunder-reporting and the exclusion of grain grown on private plots. Conversely,the kouliang is not a measure of direct human grain consumption because somecollectively-distributed grain was used as pig feed. This last apparentlimitation is an advantage in assessing living standards because the kouliangcaptures indirect consumption of grain in the form of pork.
[38]For the data, see Nongye bu1981,178.
[39]NYTJ 1976, 122-23 & 356-58;Jiangsu tongjiju 1994, 205-613. Suzhou is defined here as Jiangyin, Wuxicounty, Shazhou (contemporary Zhangjiagang), Changshu, Taicang, Kunshan, Wuxianand Wujiang counties.
[40]Constant price agriculturalvalue-added in Jiangsu rose by 2.4 per cent per year during 1965-78. If wecompare this with the rates achieved by other Asian economies early in theireconomic development, it was clearly lower than the 2.8 per cent achieved byJapan during 1955-70 (Hayami and Yamada 1991, 19), Taiwan's rate of 3.7 per centduring 1951-70 (Thorbecke 1979, 135) and South Korea's 4 per cent for 1960-75(World Bank 2017).
[41]Gao 1999; Hinton 1991.
[42]This programme is usuallyabbreviated as gangyao (纲要) in the Chinese literature,and counties meeting their yield target are often described as having achievedgangyao.
[43]The Huai was the traditionalboundary between north and south China (see Buck 1937, 9) because it marked thelimit of rice cultivation. Historically, the Huai river entered the Yellow seaat Yuntiguan in Xiangshui county. By the 1950s, however, much of the river'swater entered Lake Hongze and thence flowed south to the Yangzi; the old rivercourse was used to build the North Jiangsu Irrigation Canal. Nevertheless, theold course was adopted as the southern demarcation line for the agriculturalregion between the Huai and Yellow rivers; see the map in People's Daily on 25December 1957.
[44]Nongye bu 1960, 120-21. Chinesedata on grain yields are usually given as output per sown unit or danchan (单产). However, the gangyao targets were in terms of grain output perunit of cultivated (arable) area, or nianmuchan (年亩产);see Nongye bu 1960, 8.
[45]Parts of China had already hitthe gangyao target by 1957; there were nine gangyao counties in Sichuan andfour in Zhejiang (Nongye bu 1959, 120-21).
[46]See NYFX 1979, 317. The cities ofZhenjiang, Taizhou, Yangzhong and Nantong posted high grain yields but werepart of the counties of Dantu, Nantong, Hanjiang and Taixian respectively in1957, rather than independent county-level jurisdictions.
[47]Nonglin bu 1972, 44; Nongye bu1960, 120-21; Jiangsu tongjiju 1977, pp. 35-36.
[48]NYFX 1979, 2.
[49]The data used in Figure 3 are perunit of cultivated area to make them correspond with the gangyao targets. Theyield increase between 1957 and 1978 therefore reflected both changes inmultiple cropping and increases in yield per unit of sown area. In fact,grain-sown area declined from 119.7 million mu in 1957 to 94.7 million mu in1978, whereas grain yield per sown mu rose from 178 jin to 480 jin (NYFX 1979,2). By comparison, the grain yield per unit of sown area was 184 jin during1933-36 and 162 jin in 1952 (Jiangsu sheng nonglinting 1992, 9).
[50]HYTJ 1991, 62-64.
[51] We often think of Maoist growthas being investment-led, but of course capital is a product of labour, whetheralive or dead (we can think of the machines used to produce machines as deadlabour). It is for this reason that the mobilization of labour, and using it toproduce capital rather than consumption goods, is one of the key elements inthe development process.
[52]Jiangsu TJNJ 2006, 79.
[53]De Vries 1994.
[54]NJZ 1983, 46; Han 1992, 500.
[55]Jiangsu tongjiju 1977, 235.
[56]My argument in this section thatlate Maoist development was constrained by labour shortages is controversial insome quarters, and one anonymous referee took issue with it. However, the veryfact that the number of days worked per worker rose over time, the emphasisgiven to agricultural mechanization in the 1970s, and the abundant evidencethat double and triple cropping was often prevented by seasonal labourshortages all point in this direction. So too does the share of the populationaged 15 to 64. This fell from 60 percent in 1953 to 56 percent in 1964. By1990, it was up to 67 percent; the 1990s were therefore the era of labourabundance in China, not the 1960s. One can of course argue that there would nothave been shortages if Maoist China had adopted a 'capitalist' developmentmodel. However, it is not clear that this is a reasonable counterfactual—American hostility made extensive international trade all butimpossible before the late 1970s. This environment forced China to adopt adevelopment model which was based around mass labour mobilization; it hadlittle choice.
[57] Rice in Jiangsu yielded 515 jinper sown mu in 1965 compared with 285 jin for corn, 254 jin for potatoes and165 jin for wheat (NYTJ 1976, 42). Hybrid rice occupied 12 per cent ofrice-sown area and yielded 20 percent more per hectare than middle rice in 1978(Jiangsu tongjiju 1979, 66-67).
[58]NYTJ 1976.
[59] Perkins et al 1977, 80. Theygive grain-processing—which employed large numbers ofwomen—as an example of an area where mechanization wasgiven high priority.
[60]Other parts of China experiencedfaster population growth (growth averaged 2.1 percent nationally per yearcompared with 1.8 per cent in Jiangsu for 1952-78) but water shortages meantthey were less able to use the population ‘gift’ effectively.
[61] In Guangdong, the proportion ofnet per capita income contributed by household production rose from 33 per centin 1963-65 to 41 per cent in 1977-78; see Guangdong sheng tongjiju 1989, 78-79.Nationally, however, the household share was lower in 1977-78 (28 per cent)than it had been in 1963-65 (34 per cent); see NJZ 1983, 523.
[62]NCJJ 2000, 153-54.
[63]Huang 1990. As discussed earlier,stagnant living standards do not of themselves preclude an unfolding industrialrevolution.
[64]SSB 2010, 394.
[65]NCJJ 2000, 249, 329 and 334;Taicang xianzhi 1991, 179.
[66] Jiangsu tongjiju 1989, 135.
[67]The Great Leap Forward is omittedfor clarity, and I have divided the post-1962 period into the sub-periods of1962-70 and 1970-78.
[68]Maddison 2010.
[69]Zhejiang tongjiju 2010.
[70]Regional GDP data for Britain in1861, based on an eleven-region division (with Scotland and Wales classified asregions), reveal that the combined share of the north-west and Yorkshire in GDPwas about 18 per cent (Geary and Stark 2015. 130). Jiangsu's 1978 share inChinese GDP was less than 7 per cent and, even with Zhejiang, just over 10 percent. Including Shanghai, however, produces a Yangzi delta share of almost 18per cent (SSB 2010).
[71]The population census of 1831 putthe combined populations of Lancashire and Yorkshire at 2.7 million, 16 percent of Britain's population. Salford's population alone amounted to 430,000 in1831 (BPP 1833, xii, xix and 304). By contrast, Jiangsu's 1978 population of58.3 million was colossal by British standards, but only 6 per cent of theChinese total.
[72]Hunt 1986; Williamson 1991.
[73]Timmins 1998, 98.
[74]Jiangsu tongjiju 1989, 137
[75]The Third Front province ofSichuan recorded a 1978 share of 58 per cent. Interestingly, Guangdong's heavyindustry share (43 per cent) was a little lower than Jiangsu's (SSB 1990;Guangdong tongjiju 1989).
[76]The Third Front province ofSichuan recorded a 1978 share of 58 per cent. Interestingly, Guangdong's heavyindustry share (43 per cent) was a little lower than Jiangsu's (SSB 1990;Guangdong tongjiju 1989).
[77]Broadberry 2015, 176.
[78]Timmins 1998, 116.
[79]Timmins 1998, 116.
[80]Rodrik 2016.
[81] As an aside, note that Jiangsuwas much better-placed in the late 1970s for sustained growth than those poorcountries which have based their growth around capital inflows, aid or acommodity boom (such as Venezuela).
[82]The argument, suggestingsimilarities between Singapore and the Soviet Union, and contrasts to HongKong, was advanced by Young 1992 and subsequently popularized by Krugman 1994.
[83]For the debate, see the recentcontributions of Allen 2009, and Humphries and Schneider 2016.
[84]Ashton 1948. According to Davis(1979, 10): 'The initiative [for the industrial revolution] came from thesupply side, from technical change in the manufacture of cotton, in an industrywhich hitherto had been almost negligible and one which with its old techniqueswould have remained so.'
[85]In more theoretical terms, ashift in the aggregate production function (technical progress) is assumed tobe distinct from a movement along the function (an input increase).
[86]VonTunzelmann 1978.
[87] Broadberry 2015, 367; Crafts 2014; Antras and Voth 2003.
[88]Moreover, as Ellen Meiksins Wood (1991) reminds us, theanti-manufacturing bias of British financial capital meant that the Britishexperience demonstrates the limitations of certain types of capitalist systems.
[89] SSB 1985, 185-186.
[90] WXG 1990.
[91]NCJJ 2000; Jiangsu tongjiju 1994.
[92]Perkins et al (1981, 114) reached an equally positiveconclusion: '...the overall efficiency of these rural, small-scale plants isrelatively high, especially when considered in the light of China's level ofdevelopment."
[93]Sachs and Woo 1994.
[94]See also the discussion inBramall 2000, 166-187.
[95]Bramall 1993; 2000; 2007.

参考书目:

Allen, Robert C. 2009. The British Industrial Revolution in GlobalPerspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Antras, Pol and Hans-JoachimVoth. 2003. “Factor prices and productivity growth during the Britishindustrial revolution.” Explorations inEconomic History, 40, 52-77.
Apostolides, Alexander. 2008."English agricultural output and land productivity, 1250-1850." Athttps://ore.exeter.ac.uk/repository/handle/10871/13985 (accessed 1.9.2017).
Ashton, T. S. 1948 (reprinted1997). The Industrial Revolution1760-1830. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Banister, Judith. 1987. China's Changing Population. Stanford:Stanford University Press.
Blecher, Marc. 2009. China Against the Tides (third edition).London: Bloomsbury.
Blecher, Marc and VivienneShue. 1996. Tethered Deer. Stanford:Stanford University Press.
BPP - British ParliamentaryPapers. 1833. An act for taking anaccount of the population of Great Britain and of the increase or diminutionthereof (2 April 1833).
BPP 1839. Returns relating to Factories 1838 (20 February 1839).
Bramall, Chris. 1993. In Praise of Maoist Economic Planning. Oxford:Clarendon Press.
Bramall, Chris. 2000. Sources of Chinese Economic Growth,1978-1996. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bramall, Chris. 2007. The Industrialization of Rural China.Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bramall, Chris. (forthcoming)." Living Standards in Maoist China" in Debin Ma and Richard vonGlahn, The Cambridge Economic History ofChina, Vol.II. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Broadberry, Stephen, BruceCampbell, Alexander Klein, Mark Overton and Bas van Leeuwen. 2015. British Economic Growth 1270-1870.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Buck, John Lossing. 1937. Land Utilization in China: Atlas.Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Crafts, Nick. 1985. British Economic Growth during theIndustrial Revolution. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Crafts, Nick. 2014. ”Industrialization:Why Britain Got There First,” Universityof Warwick Working Paper no. 214 athttp://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/economics/research/centres/cage/manage/publications/214-2014_crafts.pdf(accessed 20.9.2016)
Dangdai Zhongguo de xiangzhenqiye weiyuanhui (Editorial Committee for RuralIndustry in Contemporary China). 1991. DangdaiZhongguo de xiangzhen qiye (Rural Industry in contemporary China). Beijing:Dangdai Zhongguo chubanshe
Dangdai Zhongguo de xiangzhenqiye weiyuanhui (Editorial Committee for RuralIndustry in Contemporary China). 2009. DangdaiZhongguo de xiangzhen qiye (Rural Industry in contemporary China). Beijing:Dangdai Zhongguo chubanshe.
Davis, Ralph. 1979. The Industrial Revolution and BritishOverseas Trade. Leicester: Leicester University Press.
Department of AgriculturalEconomics, University of Nanking (ed.). 1941. "The Rice Problem",April, repr. in ibid, (1980). EconomicFacts, ii. London: Garland.
De Vries, Jan. 1994. “TheIndustrial Revolution and the Industrious Revolution.” Journal of Economic History, 54(2), 249-270.
Dikötter, Frank. 2016. The Cultural Revolution. London:Bloomsbury.
FAOSTAT - Food and AgricultureOrganization of the United Nations at http://www.fao.org/faostat/en/#home(accessed 2.11.16).
Fei, Xiaotong. 1983. Chinese Village Close-Up. Beijing: NewWorld Press.
Gao, Mobo. 1999. Gao Village. London: Hurst and Company.
Gao, Mobo. 2008. The Battle for China’s Past. London:Pluto Press.
Geary, Frank and Tom Stark.2015. "Regional GDP in the UK, 1861-1911: new estimates." Economic History Review, 68 (1), 123-44.
Guangdong tongjiju (GuangdongStatistical Bureau). 1989. Guangdongguomin jingji he shehui fazhan tongji ziliao 1949-1988: Nongcun bufen (StatisticalMaterials on Guangdong's Economic and Social Development, 1949-88: RuralVolume). Guangzhou: Guangdong sheng tongjiju.
Han, Dongping. 2000. The Unknown Cultural Revolution. NewYork: Garland Publishing.
Han Zhirong. 1992. Xin Zhongguo nongchanpin jiage sishinian (Agricultural Prices during the Forty Yearsof New China). Beijing: Shuili dianli chubanshe.
Hayami, Yujiro and SaburoYamada. 1991. The AgriculturalDevelopment of Japan. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.
He, Kang (ed.). 2004. Zhongguo de xiangzhen qiye (Chineserural Industry). Beijing: Zhongguo nongye chubanshe.
Hinton, William. 1991. The Great Reversal. London: Earthscan.
Ho, Sam P. S. 1994. Rural China in Transition. Oxford:Clarendon Press.
Huang, Philip C. C. 1990. The Peasant Family and Rural Development inthe Yangzi Delta, 1350-1988. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Humphries, Jane and BenjaminSchneider. 2016. "Spinning the Industrial Revolution" athttps://www.economics.ox.ac.uk/materials/papers/14544/spinning-the-industrial-revolution-for-discussion-paper-series-final.pdf(accessed 2.09.17).
Hunt, E. H. 1986."Industrialization and Regional Inequality: Wages in Britain,1760-1914." Journal of EconomicHistory, 46, (4), 935-96.
HYTJ 1991 - Huaiyin tongji ju(Huaiyin Statistical Bureau). 1991. Huaiyinshi lishi guomin jingji tongji zhuyao zhiji (Main economic statisticalindicators for Huaiyin municipality, 1949-1990). Huaiyin: Huaiyin tongjiju.
JGK - Jiangsu shixian gaikuangweiyuanhui (Jiangsu shixian gaikuang editorial committee). 1989. Jiangsu shixian gaikuang (A Survey ofJiangsu's Cities and Counties). Nanjing: Jiangsu jiaoyu chubanshe.
Jiangsu sheng nonglinting(Jiangsu Department of Agriculture and Forestry). 1992. Jiangsu nongye fazhan shilue (ABrief History of Jiangsu's Agricultural Development). Nanjing: Jiangsukexue jishu chubanshe.
Jiangsu tongjiju (JiangsuStatistical Bureau) 1979. 1978 Jiangsusheng nongye tongji ziliao (1978 Agricultural Statistical Materials for Jiangsu).Nanjing: Jiangsu tongjiju.
Jiangsu tongjiju. 1977. 1976 Jiangsu sheng nongye tongji ziliao(1976 Agricultural Statistical Materials for Jiangsu). Nanjing: Jiangsutongjiju.
Jiangsu tongjiju. 1989. Jiangsu sishinian 1949-1989 (Forty Years ofJiangsu). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
Jiangsu tongjiju. 1994. Benxiang xiandaihua de licheng 1949-1992(Marching Along the Path to Modernization). Nanjing: Jiangsu sheng xinwenchubanshe.
Jiangsu tongjiju. 2009. Shuju jianzheng huihuang—Jiangsu 60 nian (TheData Shine Forth—60 Years of Jiangsu). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
Kelly, Morgan and CormacO'Grada. 2014. "Ready for Revolution", Warwick Working Paper no. 209at http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/economics/research/centres/cage/manage/publications/209-2014_o_grada.pdf(accessed 2.05.17).
Krugman, Paul. 1994. "TheMyth of Asia’s Miracle." ForeignAffairs, 73 (6), 62–78.
Li, Minqi. 2009. The Rise of China and the Demise of theCapitalist World-Economy. New York: Monthly Review Press.
Liu, Suinian, and Qungan Wu(eds.). 1986. China’s Socialist Economy.Beijing: Beijing Review.
Ma, Debin. 2008. “Economicgrowth in the lower Yangzi region of China.” Journal of Economic History, 68 (2), 355-392.
MacFarquhar, Roderick andMichael Schoenhals. 2006. Mao’s LastRevolution. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.
Maddison, Angus. 2010."World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1-2003 AD." Athttp://www.ggdc.net/Maddison (accessed 25.03.16).
Marton, Andrew M. 2000. China's Spatial Economic Development.London: Routledge.
Mitchell, Brian. 1988. British Historical Statistics.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mo, Yuanren. 1987. Jiangsu xiangzhen gongye fazhan shi (AHistory of the Development of Township and Village Industry in Jiangsu).Nanjing: Nanjing gongxueyuan chubanshe.
NCJJ - Jiangsu nongcun jingjiwushinian bianji weiyuanhui (Editorial Committee for Fifty Years
of Jiangsu's Rural Economy). 2000. Jiangsu nongcun jingji wushinian 1949-1999 (Jiangsu's Rural Economy1949-1999). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
NJZ - Nongmuyuye bu jihuasi(Planning Department of the Ministry of Agriculture). 1983. Nongye jingji ziliao 1949-1983 (Materials onthe Agricultural Economy 1949-1983). Beijing: Nongye chubanshe.
NYTJ - Jiangsu sheng gemingweiyuanhui nongyeju (Agriculture and Forestry Bureau of the JiangsuRevolutionary Committee). 1976. Jiangsusheng nongye tongji ziliao 1949-1975 (Agricultural Statistical Materials onJiangsu 1949-1975). Nanjing: Jiangsu sheng geming weiyuanhui nongyeju.
NYFX - Jiangsu sheng gemingweiyuanhui nonglinju (Agricultural Bureau of the Jiangsu RevolutionaryCommittee). 1979. Jiangsu sheng nongyetongji fenxian gaikuang 1949-1978 (Survey of County Agricultural Statistics forJiangsu Province 1949-1978). Nanjing: Jiangsu sheng geming weiyuanhuinonglinju.
Nonglin bu (Ministry ofAgriculture and Forestry). 1972. Nonglintongji ziliao 1971 (Agriculture andForestry Materials 1971). Zhonghua renmin gongheguo nonglin bu.
Nongye bu (Ministry ofAgriculture). 1959. Nongye jingji ziliaoshouce (Handbook of Materials on theAgricultural Economy). Beijing: Nongye chubanshe.
Nongye bu. 1960. Yijiuwuliu nian dao yijiuliuqi nian quanguonongye fazhan gangyao (The 1956-1967National Agricultural Development Plan). Beijing: Renmin chubanshe.
Nongye bu. 1981. Quanguo nongcun renmin gongshe shouyi fenpeitongji ziliao (Data on Income Distribution in China's People's Communes,1956-1980). Beijing: Nongye chubanshe.
Nongye bu. 1989. Zhongguo nongcun jingji tongji daquan (Complete Statistics on the Chinese RuralEconomy). Beijing: Nongye renmin chubanshe.
Oi, Jean C. 1989. State and Peasant in Contemporary China. Berkeley:University of California Press.
Perkins, Dwight H. 1981. Rural Small-Scale Industry in the People'sRepublic of China. Berkeley CA: University of California Press.
Riskin, Carl. 1978. “China'sRural Industries.” The China Quarterly,73, 77-98.
Riskin, Carl. 1987. China's Political Economy. Oxford:Oxford University Press.
Rodrik, Dani. 2016."Premature deindustrialisation." Journalof Economic Growth, 21, 1-33.
Sachs, Jeffrey and Wing-ThyeWoo. 1994. "Structural factors in the economic reforms of China, EasternEurope and the former Soviet Union." EconomicPolicy, 18, 101-46.
Sigurdson, Jon. 1977. Rural Industrialization in China. CambridgeMA: Harvard University Press.
SSB (State Statistical Bureau).1985. Zhongguo gongye jingji tongjiziliao (Economic StatisticalMaterials on Chinese Industry). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
SSB. 1988. Zhongguo tongji nianjian 1988 (ChineseStatistical Yearbook 1988). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
SSB. 1990. Quanguo gesheng zizhiqu zhixiashi lishi tongji ziliao huibian (Collection of Historical StatisticalMaterials on China's Provinces, Autonomous Regions and Centrally-AdministeredCities). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
SSB. 2010. Xin Zhongguo liushinian tongji ziliao huibian (Compilation of Statistical Materials for Sixty Years of New China).Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe.
Stone, Bruce. 1988. “Developmentsin agricultural technology.” The ChinaQuarterly, 118, 767-822.
Taicang xianzhi (Taicang County Records). 1991. Nanjing: Jiangsu renmin chubanshe.
Thorbecke, Erik. 1979. "AgriculturalDevelopment" in Walter Galenson (ed.). EconomicGrowth and Structural Change in Taiwan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Timmins, Geoffrey. 1998. Made in Lancashire. Manchester:Manchester University Press.
Turner, Michael. 1982."Agricultural productivity in England in the eighteenth century." Economic History Review XXXV, 4,489-510.
Von Tunzelmann, Nick. 1978. Steam Power and British Industrialization in1860. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Walder, Andrew. 2015. China under Mao. Cambridge MA: HarvardUniversity Press.
White, Lynn. Unstately Power, vol. 1. 1998. ArmonkNY: M. E. Sharpe.
Whiting, Susan H. 2001. Power and Wealth in Rural China. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.
Williamson, Jeffrey G. 1991."Did English factor markets fail during the industrial revolution?"in Nicholas Crafts, Nicholas Dimsdale and Stanley Engerman (eds.). Quantitative Economic History. Oxford:Clarendon Press.
Wood, Ellen Meiksins. 1991. The Pristine Culture of Capitalism. London:Verso.
World Bank 1992. China: Strategies for Reducing Poverty inthe 1990s. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. 2017. World Development Indicators at https://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog/world-development-indicators(accessed 10.07.2017).
Wu, Harry. 2014. China's Growth and Productivity PerformanceDebate Revisited. Athttps://www.conference-board.org/pdf_free/workingpapers/EPWP1401.pdf (accessed27.2.16).
WXG - Wuxi xian jingjiweiyuanhui (Wuxi County Economic Committee) (ed.) (1990). Wuxi xian gongye zhi (Industrial Records for Wuxi County).Shanghai: Shanghai renmin chubanshe.
Young, Alwyn. 1992. "ATale of Two Cities." In Olivier Blanchard and Stanley Fischer (eds.) 1992.NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1992. CambridgeMA, MIT Press.
Zhejiang tongjiju (ZhejiangStatistical Bureau). 2010. Zhejiangliushinian tongji ziliao huibian (Compilation of Statistics on Sixty Years ofZhejiang). Beijing: Zhongguo tongji chubanshe
Zhou, Haile. 1994. Suxichang fazhan baogao (A Report on theDevelopment of Suxichang). Beijing: Renmin ribao chubanshe


2

鲜花

握手

雷人

路过

鸡蛋

刚表态过的朋友 (2 人)

发表评论

最新评论

引用 去伪存真 2018-12-28 06:52
作为苏南人,曾亲身经历感受过文革后期家乡经济蒸蒸日上的景象,怎么也无法接受“国民经济濒临崩溃边缘”的说法!感谢此文作者所作具体详尽的资料分析分享。纠正一个小疵点:困难时期苏南农村也普遍受灾减产了,饿肚子的感觉不好受,但真没见过有哪里饿死一个人。唯一例外是外婆娘家武进县显然没受灾,清楚记得那年春节我们全家在外婆带领下倾巢而出去她娘家,放开肚子猛吃猛喝了一周,返程时还满载而归!农村的亲戚总是那么质朴热情而慷慨;因此很愤慨如今农民工上城常常遭到的歧视和虐待。

查看全部评论(1)

Archiver|红色中国网

GMT+8, 2024-4-20 00:56 , Processed in 0.016233 second(s), 12 queries .

E_mail: redchinacn@gmail.com

2010-2011http://redchinacn.net

回顶部